Growing out of this banking crisis is harder


Business Standard, 17 September 2018


In the post-1991 history, we in India have gone through two cycles of boom and bust. The investment boom of 1994 gave way to the woes of the late 1990s, and the investment boom of 2008 gave way to difficulties after 2011. The interesting question is: Why has this downturn proven more difficult to get out of? One element of the explanation is the 4 percentage points decline in inflation.

Let's start at the first boom and bust. The gross fixed assets of private non-financial firms (in the CMIE database) grew by 27.2% in 1994-95. After this, we had six adverse shocks in succession: the Asian crisis, RBI's currency defence of 1998, Vajpayee's nuclear tests, the Y2K bust, the IT bust, and then the 9/11 attacks. It is hard to overstate the gloom that came from these negative blows, coming in one after another. They kicked off a downturn, a banking crisis and a stock market crisis.

Gross fixed assets growth bottomed out at 7.7% in 2002-03: a decline of about 20 percentage points. India delivered a slew of remarkable reforms, when faced with that stress in the economy and conditions changed.

And then, we got the second boom and bust. In this boom, the gross fixed assets growth peaked again in 2008-09 at 26.7% and then went into a long decline. We have got values of 6.7% in 2015-16 followed by 7.2% in 2016-17. Once again, we got a decline of about 20 percentage points.

This story of two busts frames the story of two banking crises. In the 1999-2003 period, half of bank credit in the CMIE database sat in firms at high levels of credit stress, i.e. an interest cover ratio of worse than 1.5 for atleast two consecutive years. At the peak of the business cycle, only 15% of the bank credit was in stressed firms. In the second decline, things are a bit worse: About 60% of the bank credit is now in stressed firms.

History does not repeat itself, but it sometimes rhymes. It is very valuable to look back at the two experiences and wonder how we might get out of our difficult spot today. There was one factor in the first period, which strongly favoured banks at the expense of their customers, which is now less present. This has to do with inflation.

Earlier, CPI inflation averaged 8%. RBI had no objective, and was relaxed in responding to inflation. For the first time in its history, RBI got an objective on 20 February 2015, of 4% CPI inflation, with the signing of the Monetary Policy Framework Agreement. The inflation target was later placed in the RBI Act.

When households placed money into savings bank accounts at about 3%, and inflation was 8%, they earned about -5% real returns. When firms held current accounts at 0%, they earned about -8% real returns on these deposits. This arrangement constituted a powerful subsidy in favour of banks.

A related issue concerns sheer nominal growth. In the old days, we had 8% inflation and high GDP growth. Bank balance sheets doubled every four years. Bad assets could be hidden for a while, and the sheer growth of the balance sheet made the bad assets seem less frightening when the truth was revealed. The culture of hiding bad news got entrenched in banks and RBI.

Both these factors played in favour of banks faced with bad assets. They had to just hang in there. Every year, their profits were augmented through callable deposits that were given to them at about -6% real. Every year, their balance sheet grew sharply. Within a few years, a bad banking crisis tended to look more manageable.

These things have changed. Now, CPI inflation is about 4%. Households still earn about 3% in savings bank accounts, and their real return is about -1%. This is a difference of 4 percentage points in favour of households and against banks, when we compare the 1991-2015 experience versus the post-2015 period. Similarly, firms still get 0% for current accounts, and this translates to -4% real. This is four percentage points inferior, from the viewpoint of banks, when compared with the old days.

Banks are still unfair to callable deposits -- with negative real rates of return. But the extent to which banks earn an unfair profit by merely existing and holding deposits has gone down.

Similarly, the sheer growth of bank balance sheets has slowed. Inflation has dropped from 8% to 4%, and overall growth has slowed. Households have more choices, and that may make them less willing to keep money with banks at negative real rates. Electronic payment systems may imply that firms need smaller buffers in their current accounts. All these factors mean that bank balance sheets now grow slowly.

These factors help us understand why the second banking crisis seems harder than the previous one, even though we have the new IBC weapon. High inflation, unfairness to customers of banks, and high GDP growth created a environment where it was easier to grow out of a banking crisis. We are still unfair to customers of banks, but the macroeconomic environment has changed. Inflation is lower by 4 percentage points and nominal GDP growth is lower by more than 4 percentage points. The subsidy to banks from callable deposits has declined, and it is harder to merely let time and balance sheet growth address a banking crisis.

The one thing that has changed in the second bust, when compared with the first one, is the IBC. IBC holds the possibility of taking an asset like Bhushan Steel, which was producing 3 million tonnes of steel per year, and swiftly converting it into an asset that produces 5 million tonnes of steel per year, under the new ownership. This transformative tool was absent in the first bust. We need to dig in on the execution of IBC, so as to scale up from a few large transactions per year to a few large transactions per month.


Back up to Ajay Shah's 2018 media page
Back up to Ajay Shah's home page