To GST or not to GST


by Vijay Kelkar, Arbind Modi and Ajay Shah
Business Standard, 29 September 2025


Indirect taxation, when designed poorly, is an enemy of economic growth. We were part of the early dreams of cleaning this up by going to the `value added tax' ("VAT"), an internationally established idea, which was rebranded for India by us as the GST. This is intended to be a clean consumption tax, which is neutral to the methods of production or international trade. It is the right way to do indirect taxation in any country.

The engine of the GST is input tax credit (ITC). Comprehensive ITC eliminates the cascading of taxes, ensures that tax is levied only on the value added at each stage of production and therefore (ultimately) only on consumption, and creates a unified national market.

Today's GST, however, repeatedly violates this core principle. The system has become an example of what Lant Pritchett calls `isomorphic mimicry': it has adopted the external form of a modern GST to seek the legitimacy that comes with the name, but without the underlying function. The ITC mechanism has been increasingly obstructed by legal and procedural blockages. In many respects, the Indian GST has regressed to a tax on production, similar to the previous system of excise and service tax.

A functional GST is built on a seamless ITC system. When a business pays tax on its inputs -- materials, services, or capital goods -- it should receive a full and immediate credit. This ensures the tax is a pass-through. When ITC is blocked, the economic logic is undermined. The tax ceases to be a levy on consumption and becomes a tax on business inputs, embedding itself as a cost that cascades through the supply chain. The effective level of taxation can become very high.

One obstruction came up in the treatment of refunds under an `inverted duty structure,' which arises when inputs are taxed at a higher rate than the final output. In this situation, the excess credit should be refunded (as is done with zero-rating of exports). But, under Rule 89(5) of the CGST Rules, refunds are restricted to the tax paid on input goods only. The ITC accumulated on input services and capital goods is not refunded.

The divergence between the nominal GST rate and the effective tax burden shows the impact. For a business in the 5% slab, the blocked ITC can mean the tax incidence is higher than the nominal rate. A goods supplier might face an effective rate of 14%, while a service provider's burden can increase to 28.4%. In this form, GST is not a modern consumption tax; it is an old style tax on production.

The departure from a true VAT is not a theoretical problem; it inflicts broad, systemic damage across the economy, penalising our most dynamic sectors. Let's look at a few cases:

The services sector
This rule disproportionately affects the services sector. A manufacturer can claim refunds on its raw materials but must still accumulate input tax credit for services and capital goods. In contrast, a software or logistics firm, even though treated equitably in law, does not receive the same relief since their inputs are primarily other services and capital equipment. As a result, costs remain elevated in both manufacturing and services, but the burden is heavier in services where refunds are effectively most restricted.
Import bias
The broken credit chain has a bias in favour of imports. A domestic product may have a nominal 5 per cent GST, but its final price is inflated by uncredited taxes on its inputs, pushing the effective tax burden towards 14% or higher. An imported equivalent, however, is taxed cleanly at the border at the nominal rate. This puts domestic producers at a structural disadvantage. The disadvantage is sharper for services, where blocked credits on inputs and capital goods push the effective incidence even higher, further eroding competitiveness.
Investment
The GST has become a tax on investment. Credit for GST paid on capital goods is often deferred until a project is operational and generates its own tax liability. But a credit of Rs.100 today is worth more than a credit of Rs.100 in three years. This delay raises the cost of capital.
Anti-export bias
Exporters under GST are not fully neutralized for embedded taxes, since refunds exclude ITC on capital goods. The international best practice is to zero-rate exports completely, so that we never tax foreigners. Our rules try to tax foreign buyers and hamper the competitiveness of Indian exporters.
MSMEs
The ITC blockage weighs far more heavily on MSMEs. Larger firms can manage refunds, restructure supply chains, or absorb financing costs. MSMEs, operating with thin margins and limited access to credit, lack such flexibility. Their costs stay elevated, their competitiveness erodes, and they face a deeper import bias. The tax system, therefore, penalises smaller firms disproportionately.

Within the logic of the flawed system, the `GST 2.0' reforms of September 2025 has unfortunately made things worse. By merging the 12% slab into the 5% slab, the range of goods under cascading taxes went up and high effective production taxation rates have emerged.

The traditional GST reform agenda has focused on two goals: achieving a single rate with a comprehensive base and improving the treatment of imports and exports. A third priority must now be added: the restoration of a purist Input Tax Credit mechanism, to create a genuine GST/VAT.

We have long written about the fundamental reforms of indirect taxation in India [link, link]. The blockage of ITC is a first order problem. We have to drop everything and solve this. The path forward requires a three-pronged approach:

  1. The law must be amended to guarantee flow-based, immediate, and full ITC across all inputs: goods, services, and capital goods.
  2. Once the credit chain is fixed, the rate structure should be rationalised by merging the lower rates upwards into a single, revenue-neutral rate of around 12-14%.
  3. Finally, the administration of refunds requires improvement. Refunds are a persistent problem in VAT systems, but India has the technology to address this. A GST-CPC (Central Processing Centre), modelled on the successful Income-Tax CPC, could automate return processing and issue refunds based on risk-based checks.

Back up to the media page for the year
Back up to Ajay Shah's home page