What can fiscal policy do?


Business Standard, 27 January 2020


We are in a business cycle downturn and in a decline of trend growth. The tools of macro policy can address the business cycle, but their ability to address the overall problem are limited. We have to be cautious about fiscal expansion, given that the initial condition is one of chronic fiscal weakness. The useful path lies in harnessing the situation to push for the required long-term structural reforms in tax policy and tax administration, instead of thinking in terms of discretionary fiscal policy.

There was a great phase of high trend growth in India from about 1991 to 2011. After that, trend growth has declined. Layered on top of the long term trend is a business cycle phenomenon, of fluctuations in profitability, inventory and investment that move around the long term trend. Right now, we also have a business cycle slowdown.

At first blush, it appears that the tools of macro policy, fiscal policy and monetary policy, must ride to the rescue. Monetary policy is already doing this, owing to inflation targeting. The 91 day tbill rate, which is the best measure of the de facto stance of monetary policy, was at 11 per cent in 2013 when RBI was pursuing an exchange rate objective. Now that RBI pursues an inflation objective, it stands at 5 per cent. This is a decline of the de facto policy rate by 6 percentage points. As long as the MPC carefully peers one year out, and tries to figure out the interest rate that will deliver on the 4% CPI inflation target, monetary policy will be about right.

What about fiscal policy? Can we cut tax rates sharply and thus improve purchasing power? Or raise spending sharply, to the same effect? There are a few concerns about going down this path.

We must keep in mind that the decline in private corporate investment, that has taken place from the peak of 2007-08 till today, is a large one. Fiscal policy in India can shift its stance by one or two percentage points of GDP, but the problem is about five times larger than that.

The way in which the government borrows is faulty. Most of the borrowing takes place from captive lenders through financial repression. When the conscription runs out of steam, financial regulators may be asked to push up the forced investments in government bonds e.g. by raising the SLR. This would be a reversal of economic reforms, and raise the effective taxation upon formal financial intermediation.

Wen the economy thinks that tax rates can go up or down depending on the situation, this raises uncertainty. Private persons require stability of tax policy on multi-decade horizons in order to feel confident about investment plans.

In an ideal world, we would have had a 4% primary surplus in the boom year, 2007-08, which would have created space for a swing of 8 percentage points to a primary deficit of 4% in 2020-21. Unfortunately, fiscal policy in India does not do large surpluses in good times. Consequently, we do not come into this downturn from a position of strength. Nominal GDP growth and the average cost of borrowing of the government are rather close to each other, and there is the possibility of getting into a zone of an increasing debt/GDP ratio.

"Above all, do no harm" is an important adage in macro policy, as it is in most walks of life. Policy makers in India were in terrible bind in 2001 owing to fiscal stress and in 2010 owing to inflation. These experiences should not be forgotten. We should not add a fiscal crisis or an inflation crisis by 2022, to our list of problems.

How can fiscal policy navigate this situation? A pre-requisite lies in undertaking the PDMA and bond market reform, so as to set the stage for a healthy relationship between the government and its lenders, and create the ability to borrow from voluntary lenders on a larger scale. This requires resurrecting the work program that was initiated in 2015.

We should use this moment to push the required long-term structural changes of tax policy, all of which happen to coincide with lower tax rates. We need to go to a clean and simple Direct Tax Code, with a flat low rate of about 20 per cent for corporations and individuals. We need to go to a universal base, single rate GST of about 8 to 10 per cent. Alongside this, we need a new Tax Administration law, which brings rule of law into tax administration.

These are the required long-run structural reforms. If such changes are positioned as short-term responses to economic stress, the private sector will see them as impermanent, and the full gains to the economy will not be obtained. Hence, they should be positioned as permanent structural reforms, and not as fleeting responses to present stress. This will elicit the desired response of optimism and respect of the private sector.

There is a role for such sophisticated discussions about how macro policy can help address the slowdown. However, we should not exaggerate what macro policy can do. Monetary policy in India is limited because of the lack of financial reforms which would have given an effective monetary policy transmission. Fiscal policy in India is limited owing to chronic deficits and faulty procedures for borrowing. The standard tools of macro policy, in the Indian setting, have low potency. And, in any case, they can only address business cycle fluctuations; they cannot impact upon trend growth.

Root cause analysis of the decline in trend growth from 2011 onwards will take us to the decline in private investment. The root cause solutions will lie in going to the foundations of private unease, and addressing them. This will take us to the problems of rule of law: in the criminal justice system, the judiciary, tax administration, and economic regulation. It will also take us to the larger problem of economic freedom, of emphasising personal agency and scaling back state activism.


Back up to Ajay Shah's 2020 media page
Back up to Ajay Shah's home page